Abstract:Entrepreneurial opportunity window affects the first-action and late-action decision-making of entrepreneurial enterprises. The z-Tree system simulates the decision-making process of first and late start-up enterprises based on the market entry order, recruiting 60 college students to participate in the experiment, and uses the rank sum test model to process the data collected by the experiment. The main conclusions include: 1) When the opportunity window is not opened, the first start-ups always have market advantages, while the second start-ups have market disadvantages. The advantage gap between the two types of start-ups is relatively fixed. 2) Under the technology opportunity window, the change of technology gap between first start-ups and second start-ups has a significant impact on the output and profit of first start-ups, but has no significant impact on the output and profit of second start-ups. Second start-ups can narrow the market advantage gap between first start-ups and second start-ups by developing technology. 3) Under the institutional opportunity window, the change of institutional cost has a significant impact on the profits of first and second start-ups. The government can adjust the change of market advantage between the two types of start-ups through institutional cost.
彭华涛, 李冰冰, 曾宇. 机会窗视角下创业企业的次序决策机制研究[J]. 复杂系统与复杂性科学, 2021, 18(4): 30-42.
PEGN Huatao, LI Bingbing, ZENG Yu. On the Order Decision Mechanism of Start-up Enterprises from the Perspective of Opportunity Window. Complex Systems and Complexity Science, 2021, 18(4): 30-42.
[1]Bergek A, Berggren C, Magnusson T, et al. Technological discontinuities and the challenge for incumbent firms: destruction, disruption or creative accumulation?[J]. IEEE Engineering Management Review,2013,42(7):1210-1224. [2]Buckley P J, Hashai N. The role of technological catch up and domestic market growth in the genesis of emerging country based multinationals[J]. Research Policy,2014, 43(2):423-437. [3]Park T Y, Krishnan R T, Booth D. Catching-up or leapfrogging in the indian IT service sector: windows of opportunity, path-creating, and moving up the value chain[J]. Development Policy Review,2014, 32(4):495-518. [4]Guennif S, Ramani S V. Explaining divergence in catching-up in pharma between India and Brazil using the NSI framework[J]. Research Policy,2016,41(2):430-441. [5]Figueiredo, Paulo N. Beyond technological catch-up:an empirical investigation of further innovative capability accumulation outcomes in latecomer firms with evidence from Brazil[J]. Journal of Engineering and Technology Management, 2014, 31(1):73-102. [6]Malerba F, Nelson R. Learning and catching up in different sectoral systems: evidence from six industries[J]. Industrial & Corporate Change,2012, 20(6): 1645-1675. [7]Giachetti C, Marchi G. Successive changes in leadership in the worldwide mobile phone industry, the role of windows of opportunity and firms'competitive action[J]. Research Policy, 2017, 46(2): 352-364. [8]Paolo D M, Rodney T J. Entrepreneurial opportunity pursuit through business model transformation: a project perspective[J]. International Journal of Project Management, 2018, 36(7): 968-979. [9]Sounman H, Sanghyun L. Adaptive governance and decentralization:evidence from regulation of the sharing economy in multi-level governance[J]. Government Information Quarterly, 2018, 35(2): 299-305. [10] Cantwell J A. Blurred boundaries between firms, and new boundaries within (large multinational) firms:the impact of decentralized networks for innovation[J]. Seoul Journal of Economics, 2013, 26(1): 1-32. [11] 汪俊,吴岳慧. 基于先动优势的企业竞争优势保持研究[J].企业技术开发, 2011, 30(1): 9-10. Wang Jun, Wu Yuehui.Research on enterprise competitive advantage maintenance based on first-mover advantage [J]. Technology Development, 2011,30(1):9-10. [12] 杨湘玉,程源.企业异质性假设和企业先动优势的机制分析[J].生产力研究, 2008(8):21-22,43. Yang Xiangyu, Cheng Yuan.Hypothesis of firm heterogeneity and mechanism analysis of firms' first-mover advantage [J]. Productivity Research, 2008(8):21-22,43. [13] 郝喜玲,朱兆珍,刘依冉.失败情境下创业学习、创业知识与再创业绩效关系研究[J].科技进步与对策, 2019, 36(16):19-25. Hao Xiling, Zhu Zhaozhen, Liu Yiran. A study on the mechanism of the effect of learning from entrepreneurial failure on entrepreneurial knowledge and new venture performance[J].Science & Technology Progress and Policy, 2019, 36(16):19-25. [14] 尹苗苗,刘玉国.新企业战略倾向对创业学习的影响研究[J].科学学研究,2016, 34(8):1223-1231. Yin Miaomiao, Liu Yuguo. Research on the effect of strategic propensity on new ventures' entrepreneurial learning[J]. Studies in Science of Science, 2016, 34(8):1223-1231. [15] 尹锦霞,高凌云,胡春艳.基于市场竞争优势差异的不对称双头垄断投资决策模型——对中小微企业发展路径的一种理论解释[J].科技管理研究, 2016, 36(12):226-230. Yin Jinxia, Gao Lingyun, Hu Chunyan. Asymmetrical duopoly investment decision-making model based on the difference between the market competitive advantages[J]. Science and Technology Management Research, 2016, 36(12):226-230. [16] 陈积志,任方旭.双寡头垄断市场下研发投入竞争的决策选择[J].统计与决策, 2010(7):38-41. Chen Jizhi, Ren Fangxu.The decision and choice of R&D investment competition in duopoly market [J]. Statistics & Decision, 2010(7):38-41. [17] 曲永军,毕新华.后发地区战略性新兴产业成长动力研究[J].社会科学战线, 2014(5):245-247. Qu Yongjun, Bi Xinhua. Research on the growth impetus of strategic emerging industries in late-developing regions [J].Social Science Front, 2014(5):245-247. [18] 郭晓丹,宋维佳.战略性新兴产业的进入时机选择:领军还是跟进[J].中国工业经济, 2011(5):119-128. Guo Xiaodan, Song Weijia. The choice of timing to enter the strategic emerging industries: leading or following [J].China Industrial Economics, 2011(5):119-128. [19] Landini F, Lee K, Malerba F. A history-friendly model of the successive changes in industrial leadership and the catch-up by latecomers[J]. Research Policy,2016,46(2):431-446. [20] 彭桥,肖尧,陈浩. 政府补贴、产业结构升级与阶段效应——基于古诺模型的分析框架[J]. 工业技术经济,2020,39(5):119-126. Peng Qiao, Xiao Yao, Chen Hao. Government subsidies, industrial upgrading and phase effect—analysis framework based on cournot model[J]. Journal of Industrial Technological Economics, 2020,39(5):119-126. [21] 罗军.基于Stackelberg模型的供应中断惩罚机制研究[J].统计与决策,2020,36(8):170-173. Luo Jun.Research on supply interruption punishment mechanism based on stackelberg model [J].Statistics & Decision, 2020,36(8):170-173. [22] Stamatopoulos G. Cournot and stackelberg equilibrium under strategic delegation: an equivalence result[J]. Theory and Decision, 2016, 81(4):553-570. [23] Lee K, Ki J H. Rise of latecomers and catch-up cycles in the world steel industry[J]. Research Policy, 2016, 46(2):365-375. [24] Keun L, Franco M. Catch-up cycles and changes in industrial leadership:windows of opportunity and responses of firms and countries in the evolution of sectoral systems[J]. Research Policy, 2017,46(2):338-351. [25] 彭新敏, 姚丽婷. 机会窗口、动态能力与后发企业的技术追赶[J]. 科学学与科学技术管理, 2019,40(6):68-82. Peng Xinmin, Yao Liting. Wind of opportunity, dynamic capability and latecomer firms' technological catch-up[J]. Science of Science and Management of S & T, 2019,40(6):68-82. [26] Yap X S, Truffer B. Shaping selection environments for industrial catch-up and sustainability transitions: a systemic perspective on endogenizing windows of opportunity[J]. Research Policy, 2018, 45(2):1-16. [27] Normann, Kon E. The role of politics in sustainable transitions: the rise and decline of offshore wind in Norway[J]. Environmental Innovation & Societal Transitions, 2015, 15:180-193. [28] Tongur S, Engwall M.Exploring window of opportunity dynamics in infrastructure transformation[J]. Environmental Innovation and Societal Transitions, 2017,25:82-93. [29] Vertesy D. Preconditions, windows of opportunity and innovation strategies: successive leadership changes in the regional jet industry[J]. Research Policy, 2017, 46(2):388-403.